色花堂's emeritus Professor Nigel Jump writes the latest in his series of blogs on the Dorset economy.
The State has increased its share of, and role in, the economy in recent times.聽Since the changes wrought by Brexit and COVID-19,
- Many expect the government to solve problems with unemployment, growth, and inflation, as well as a wide range of other socio-economic issues
- Few remember that, ultimately, nearly all government spending comes from taxation on the private sector, through current tax receipts or loans repaid later.聽
Calls for government intervention in the economy implicitly say, 鈥the Treasury can use my money better than I can鈥.聽Objectively analysed, this can be true or false on an individual case basis.聽More subjectively, this choice often underlies political debate.聽It seems to have become more difficult to agree on the right balance between public and private activity in particular industries and/or services.聽
First, some facts.
UK public sector net debt increased over 40% from 拢1,835bn to 拢2,599bn between the end of 2019 and the end of June 2023.聽Since 2010, the UK鈥檚 public debt is up almost 150%. Net debt is now about 100% of GDP 鈥 a level that used to be associated with 鈥榯hird world鈥 basket cases.聽Given the recent modest performance of consumer spending, private investment and exports, real GDP is only above pre-pandemic levels because of government spending. This is reflected in the large rise in public-sector employment versus a fall in private-sector employment since 2019. The State is huge, creating high debts and deficits, but it is not always efficient.聽From HS2 to the NHS, there is popular frustration with the effectiveness of many State operations.
Second, some analysis.聽
After recent 鈥榮hocks鈥 to the system, the UK economy has experienced a 鈥榮uper鈥 Keynesian expansion in the role of government in the economy. At the same time, there has been a massive monetary injection through Quantitative Easing.聽The economy, awash with 鈥榰nproductive鈥 money, has an inflation problem.
An expanding State as a share of GDP is unlikely to yield a productivity-driven, sustainably growing, economy.聽Historically, if the government redistributes more of the nation鈥檚 income and wealth, a lower growth potential tends to result.聽Moreover, an economy dependent on State expenditure is not one where taxes or interest rates can be lowered easily.聽Debt ratios are higher than they used to be in many countries, but ours seems to be one of the more intractable.
Meanwhile, monetary policy is a mess. Quantitative Easing ballooned the Bank of England鈥檚 reserves, ending up as deposits on bank balance sheets. Banks have held more deposits than they would otherwise have done, whilst the central bank has fixed interest rates below inflation.聽With a rise in base rates to 5.25%, banks are vulnerable to holding assets that they bought at much lower interest rates/higher real prices.聽Hopefully, economic behaviour will now adjust back to the 鈥榥orm鈥 of positive real interest rates, but it may be painful getting there for a range of borrowers, including the government.
At the ballot box (and in general discourse), we choose the scale of the State together with how, and on what, it spends our money.聽We choose where the State will intervene and at what cost, both now and for future generations.聽In turn, this determines the direction of specific spending and taxation policies and, importantly, sets key behavioural incentives for businesses and households.
Local economic development reflects the level and growth of productivity.聽In turn, productivity reflects investment, innovation, skills, entrepreneurship, and competitiveness.聽Given the 鈥楤ig State鈥 highlighted here, the forthcoming election needs to include conscious decisions about how to make fiscal and monetary policies more effective = productivity-enhancing.聽聽
Increasing the long-term growth rate is the avowed focus of many policymakers. Most political parties cite 鈥榞rowth鈥 as the key to success (as we heard throughout the recent party conference season).聽They all claim to have policies for growth but have yet to outline fully convincing answers.聽The next electoral 鈥榳inners鈥 will start from a point of great weakness in the fiscal and monetary numbers.聽They need to explain which fiscal levers their State is going to pull in order to boost which productivity drivers.聽
- There are areas where the government needs to get out of the way 鈥 where the State detracts from growth - e.g., some aspects of regulation and service provision
- There are areas for government to engage - where the private sector cannot or will not drive public values - e.g., where future returns are hard to assess/resolve and/or where international cooperation would be advantageous 鈥 such as aspects of economic 鈥榞reening鈥
- There are areas of value that the people want addressed e.g., cost of living, health and education, and climate and environment.
The State is an important economic player.聽Sometimes it makes things worse and sometimes it intervenes effectively.聽The traumatic years since 2016 have increased peoples鈥 expectations about what the State can and should do, especially where the private sector has proved unreliable or 鈥榞reedy鈥.聽
The growing State has not delivered in important areas.聽We need to think carefully about whether the State is too big or too small.聽Clarification of 鈥榟ow, when and where鈥 the government should allocate resources is required.聽We need efficient and effective interventions, rigorously tested against objective data and analytical criteria.聽Faced with a scarcity of funding, the State must make difficult choices.聽We all need to interrogate closely the different 鈥榦ffers鈥 before reaching a viable consensus.